Navigation

    Voting Theory Forum

    • Register
    • Login
    • Search
    • Recent
    • Categories
    • Tags
    • Popular
    • Users
    • Groups

    Fixing Participation Failure in “Approval vs B2R”

    Single-winner
    2
    3
    30
    Loading More Posts
    • Oldest to Newest
    • Newest to Oldest
    • Most Votes
    Reply
    • Reply as topic
    Log in to reply
    This topic has been deleted. Only users with topic management privileges can see it.
    • C
      cfrank last edited by cfrank

      DISCLAIMER: This is conjectural and needs adjustments, but at least participation compliance can be improved. I have had LLMs run thousands of examples of this iteration, and have found no examples of participation failure. Still, it needs to be audited closely.

      To understand this method, you should also know about Bottom Two Runoff (B2R), which you can learn about here for example:

      https://www.votingtheory.org/forum/topic/564/bottom-n-and-bottom-2-runoffs-are-equivalent

      The method is a development of this concept:

      https://www.votingtheory.org/forum/topic/563/direct-independent-condorcet-validation/20

      Consider the following method, which I’m just calling Approval vs. B2R, similar to Approval-seeded Llull as per @Jack-Waugh ---it's a bit technical, but there's a reason for that, so bear with me:

      DEFINITION

      (1) Voters submit rank ballots with approval cutoffs.
      (2) Candidates are sorted by approval rates, with rank-based head-to-head breaking ties if possible. If approval ties cannot be broken by head-to-heads (when they are also tied), introduce an authoritative participant with a consistent rank-order over the candidates to break the ties.
      (3) According to this sorting order, run B2R and identify the B2R winner, with head-to-head ties broken by the sorting order.
      (4) Compute the maximum approval rating. If the B2R winner attains this rate, and NO OTHER candidates do, then elect the B2R winner (who is also the approval winner).
      (5) Otherwise, among top-approved candidates who are different from the B2R winner, select the one with the tightest margin against the B2R winner, with ties determined by the sorting. They will be the B2R winner's adversary.
      (6) Run a secondary, independent head-to-head election between the B2R winner and their adversary, with the following caveats:

      --> Voters are not tied down in any way to their original preference between the B2R winner and the adversary, and can freely vote for either in the independent head-to-head. Also, voters who did not participate in the first round are fully allowed to participate in the final round. By default, voters' original ballots will be used to determine the preference, but voters may opt in to swap their rating either 0 or 1 times, whichever amount is necessary to indicate an advantage that they wish to disclose.
      --> However, based on these swaps, we can count the net number of swaps that are advantageous to the adversary over the B2R winner compared with the original ballots. If this number is positive, the election proceeds as you would expect, with ties broken by the sort order. However, if the number is not positive, if the original head-to-head was in favor of the B2R survivor, and if a material difference would be incurred, then the adversary will be conferred an automatic +1 head-to-head advantage, and will also automatically win ties.

      I conjecture that these caveats about the runoff—including setting aside the B2R winner, increasing the Approval contender’s advantage by +1, and giving them ties—together restore the participation criterion under fully sincere ballots, at the expense of the full Condorcet criterion. However, when the margins are not close, the Condorcet criterion is still satisfied if ballots are sincere.

      Here’s what else is fascinating about this: we can directly control the tradeoff between participation and Condorcet—in particular, when applicable, we can choose to increase the B2R adversary's margin over the B2R winner by +1 with probability P. Then the method satisfies participation under sincere ballots with probability at least P, and simultaneously satisfies the Condorcet criterion under sincere ballots with probability at least 1-P.

      IN SUMMARY:

      This method I believe is participation compliant, which it is supposed to be by intentional design. This still needs to be proved. But as a consequence of this intention, it was also designed to fail Condorcet compliant in a controlled way. As per my comprehension, it will fail Condorcet compliance under these exact conditions:

      (1) The Condorcet winner C exists (and will therefore be the B2R survivor);
      (2) The approval winner Y is different from C;
      (3) The head-to-head rank-based margin of C over Y is either 0 or +1; and
      (4) The +1 boost to Y is applied, with ties going to Y.

      More generally, it will fail the Smith criterion under these exact conditions:

      (1) The approval winner Y is not in the Smith set;
      (2) The head-to-head rank-based margin of the B2R survivor over Y is either 0 or +1; and
      (3) The +1 boost to Y is applied, with ties going to Y.

      In all other cases, it satisfies the Smith criterion. Thus in a sense, this method tries to be as close to Smith compliant as possible while enforcing participation compliance as non-negotiable. It unconditionally satisfies a weakened version of the Condorcet criterion: If the Condorcet winner exists and its weakest margin of victory is at least 2, then the Condorcet winner is elected. It also unconditionally satisfies a more significantly weakened version of the Smith criterion: If every member of the Smith set has a weakest margin of victory against non-Smith set members of at least 2, then the election winner will belong to the Smith set.

      Not that it's necessary to frame the properties in terms of Smith or Condorcet criterion-sounding conditions, but possibly those weak conditions can be strengthened. It is what it is.

      Future work will be to prove participation and to refine the mechanisms for guaranteeing participation.

      score-stratified-condorcet [10] cardinal-condorcet [9] ranked-condorcet [8] score [7] approval [6] ranked-bucklin [5] star [4] ranked-irv [3] ranked-borda [2] for-against [1] distribute [0] choose-one [0]

      T 1 Reply Last reply Reply Quote 0
      • T
        Toby Pereira @cfrank last edited by

        @cfrank said in Fixing Participation Failure in “Approval vs B2R”:

        (6) Run a secondary, independent head-to-head election between the B2R winner and their adversary, with the following caveats:
        --> Voters are not tied down in any way to their original preference between the B2R winner and the adversary, and can freely vote for either in the independent head-to-head. Also, voters who did not participate in the first round are fully allowed to participate in the final round. By default, voters' original ballots will be used to determine the preference, but voters may opt in to swap their rating either 0 or 1 times, whichever amount is necessary to indicate an advantage that they wish to disclose.
        --> However, based on these swaps, we can count the net number of swaps that are advantageous to the adversary over the B2R winner compared with the original ballots. If this number is positive, the election proceeds as you would expect, with ties broken by the sort order. However, if the number is not positive, if the original head-to-head was in favor of the B2R survivor, and if a material difference would be incurred, then the adversary will be conferred an automatic +1 head-to-head advantage, and will also automatically win ties.

        I find this part a bit hard to understand.

        Also, if it's an independent head-to-head, do you mean a separate trip to the polling station, or just a separate part of the ballot paper? If it's a separate trip, then it would be impossible to manage the swaps and each voter's default position without losing anonymity.

        C 1 Reply Last reply Reply Quote 1
        • C
          cfrank @Toby Pereira last edited by cfrank

          @toby-pereira yes it’s a bit particular, that’s the part that’s designed to preserve participation. The +1 advantage plus tie break conferred to the adversary is essentially to prevent any single vote from changing the outcome of the participation criterion-satisfying method. It still needs proof or more auditing and adjustment. But it was motivated empirically by finding examples of participation failure without introducing the advantage and some other aspects.

          I think voters could have an anonymous ID given to them upon voting, it would have to be done with encryption. You’re right that in this case we would have to preclude latecomers, which I think would be fine. I think it could be done securely without an extra trip. This whole situation really makes “recounts” potential difficult though.

          Having the “sincere” rank be attached to the original ballot might also be an option, but voters would somehow need to know that the second ballot would not be used in the first election, for instance. The only way they can know for sure is if they don’t provide it until after the first election winners are revealed. That could also be done with encryption.

          In terms of preserving participation, the final runoff may not even be necessary. I’m trying to combine two things that can be looked at separately.

          Also thanks for reading and your thoughts! I’m starting to wonder about how to guarantee the Condorcet loser criterion while still preserving participation. As of now though I think the method is essentially approval but with significantly stronger Condorcet-like guarantees.

          score-stratified-condorcet [10] cardinal-condorcet [9] ranked-condorcet [8] score [7] approval [6] ranked-bucklin [5] star [4] ranked-irv [3] ranked-borda [2] for-against [1] distribute [0] choose-one [0]

          1 Reply Last reply Reply Quote 0
          • First post
            Last post